Hot time, summer in the city

In ongoing downtown revitalization efforts, various summer activities are underway-including lunch hour live music on Thursdays at Cheapside Park from 12:15 to 1:15 pm and Thursday Night Live from 5:30 to 7:30 pm.

On Fridays, artists can come to the Old Courthouse Square and color the sidewalks with chalk. Selected streets will close to traffic and feature live jazz and downtown vendors offering food and drink to give a New Orleans-type atmosphere (Hope there's no second line brass bands).

Saturdays will feature Artists'' Market at Triangle Park for artists to display and sell works, conveniently located within walking distance of Farmers' Market.

Thoroughbred Park will feature live music.


Moms Online

Club Mom, a free membership organization devoted to bringing mothers together to share ideas, along with providing information and interactive tools now has a message board for the Lexington area. Gretchen Nalley of Versailles will serve as the Board Moderator, who says, "Time is in short supply for moms in general, and new moms in particular. This allows moms to get together online and exchange information, offer advice, keep up with what's new, find out what is going on in the area, and discuss their concerns with other mothers any time they want."

Nalley is the author and publisher of The Baby Web, The Directory Of Baby-Related Websites. Access the Lexington Board by logging on to www.ClubMom.com and clicking on Lexington in the Club Mom Local section. Or e-mail Gretchen Nalley at gnalley@chestnutlanedesign.com for info.


Something completely different.

To celebrate their one-year anniversary on the web, the Brains on Film site now has an interactive message board. Visit these fine folks (Larry Treadway et al.) at brainsonfilm.com. (Many years ago, Brains on Film was Ace's movie column.)


Over a billion served

After years of being targeted to raise the standards on farms and at slaughterhouses, McDonald's has begun a campaign to dispatch animals more humanely and revisit the standards for industrial/factory farming practices. A documentary will air on WEKU, "Fast Food and Animal Rights-McDonald's New Farm." Wednesday, June 26 at 7 p.m. on WEKU 88.9FM in Richmond, WEKH 90.9FM in Hazard and live on-line at www.weku.fm.

.
GUEST OPINION

A Bitter Pill
by Russell Mokhiber and Robert Weissman


Drug prices in the United States are out of control, and rising.

The reason is that the United States permits pharmaceuticals to be marketed by unregulated monopolies: Patent protection gives the drug companies monopoly control over their products.

These companies face neither direct competition, nor price controls.

But what is the reason for the government grant of these patent monopolies (which often extend long beyond the official 20 years, thanks to a variety of Big Pharma "evergreening" tactics to block or delay the introduction of generic competition)?

Leaving aside the raw political power of the pharmaceutical industry and its allies, the policy rationale for patent monopolies is the cost of drug development. According to the drug companies, the cost of researching and developing a new drug is $800 million.

The myth of astronomical drug development costs is the figleaf behind which Big Pharma and its paid associates (inside and outside of government) hide to escape criticism for price gouging.

If this myth were peeled away, Big Pharma would stand exposed. And the prospect of a more rational system of drug development and pricing would rise dramatically.

This matter could be resolved, simply, if the drug companies were to open their books and reveal their actual investments in R&D. Instead, they implausibly claim that this information would give away trade secrets and must remain proprietary.

The industry claim of $800 million costs per drug relies on a study from an industry-funded research center at Tufts University in Boston. Tufts researchers supposedly had access to industry data to come up with their figure, but no one else is able to see the underlying data.

To get closer to the actual figures for the cost of drug development and company per drug expenditures on R&D, you have to peel away the assumptions and built-in biases of the Tufts-industry study.

Approximately half of the Tufts-industry estimates are attributed to financing costs, known as opportunity cost of capital. Money invested in drug R&D could have been invested in treasury bonds, say. While the bonds would start returning revenues right away, R&D returns are not realized for years, until a drug is discovered, developed, approved, and put on the market. So in the Tufts-industry study, a "cost" of development is the forsworn income during the period of development.

This is all true, as far it goes, but it is not how people normally think about "cost." As James Love of the Consumer Project on Technology says, it is the equivalent of saying the cost of a car is not the sticker price, but the sticker price plus interest payments on a car loan.

Exacerbating the problem, the researchers may pick an unreasonably high interest rate. They may also set the period for drug development as too long-in the Tufts-industry model, relatively small delays in getting the drug to market lead to big increases in the overall cost.

The Tufts-industry estimate is for the cost of new chemical entities for which the industry was wholly responsible-that is, where there was no substantial public contribution to R&D.

It turns out, however, that the vast majority of new drugs Big Pharma brings to market do not involve new chemical compounds. A May 2002 study by the National Institute for Health Care Management (NIHCM) Foundation found that two-thirds of the prescription drugs approved by the FDA between 1989 and 2000 were modified versions of existing medicines or identical to drugs already on the market (and only about 15 percent were both new and deemed by the FDA to provide significant improvement over existing medicines). Pharma denies it, but there is every reason to believe these less novel products are far cheaper to bring to market.

Then there's the not-insignificant fact that the case of drugs brought to market without government support is the exception, not the norm. The federal government supports an enormous amount of research, and funds the earliest and riskiest portions of the R&D process: basic research and the earlier phases of clinical trials.

Finally, the Tufts-industry figures seem to wildly inflate the cost of clinical testing. Looking at company filings with the IRS for tax credits on research for "orphan drugs" (drugs which treat small populations), however, the Consumer Project on Technology found that-adjusted for risk-drug companies report expenditures of only $7.9 million on clinical trials, less than 1 percent of the overall estimate.

Even if the costs for this category of drug are below average, as the industry claims-even if they were, implausibly, a tenth of the average-this would still suggest a much lower total development cost than the Tufts-industry estimate.

Any honest examination of available evidence on the costs of drug development suggests the United States-and most of the rest of the world, which thanks to the U.S./industry strong-arming tactics in international trade negotiations, now maintains or soon will adopt U.S.-style patent rules-is massively overcompensating the pharmaceutical industry for its work in bringing drugs to market.

With the U.S. healthcare system bursting at the seams, seniors draining their bank accounts to buy drugs, and millions of people around the world going without medicines, the time has come for fundamental reform.

Meaningful reform might include ending the industry's patent extension tricks, licensing drugs developed with public monies on a nonexclusive basis to permit price-reducing competition (or at least permitting competition where prices are excessive), and considering rollbacks to the 20-year patent term and the adoption of price controls.

 
HOME | THIS ISSUE | ACE ARCHIVES